The "reluctant revolutionaries," as the leaders of the multiclass Nationalist
Revolutionary Movement (MNR) were called by some, looked more to Mexico
than to the
Soviet Union for a model. But during the first year of Victor Paz Estenssoro's
presidency, the radical faction in the party, which had gained strength
during the
sexenio when the party embraced the workers and their ideology, forced
the MNR leaders to act quickly. In July 1952, the government established
universal
suffrage, with neither literacy nor property requirements. In the first
postrevolutionary elections in 1956, the population of eligible voters
increased from
approximately 200,000 to nearly 1 million voters. The government also
moved quickly to control the armed forces, purging many officers associated
with past
Conservative Party regimes and drastically reducing the forces' size
and budget. The government also closed the Military Academy and required
that officers take an oath to the MNR.
The government then began the process of nationalizing all mines of
the three great tin companies. First, it made the export and sale of all
minerals a state monopoly
to be administered by the state-owned Mining Bank of Bolivia. Then
it set up the Mining Corporation of Bolivia (Comibol) as a semiautonomous
enterprise to run
state-owned mines. On October 31, 1952, the government nationalized
the three big tin companies, leaving the medium-sized mines untouched,
and promising
compensation. In this process, two-thirds of Bolivia's mining industry
was turned over to Comibol.
A far-reaching agrarian reform was the final important step taken by
the revolutionary government. In January 1953, the government established
the Agrarian Reform
Commission, using advisers from Mexico, and decreed the Agrarian Reform
Law the following August. The law abolished forced labor and established
a program of
expropriation and distribution of the rural property of the traditional
landlords to the Indian peasants. Only estates with low productivity were
completely distributed.
More productive small and medium-sized farms were allowed to keep part
of their land and were encouraged to invest new capital to increase agricultural
production. The Agrarian Reform Law also provided for compensation
for landlords to be paid in the form of twenty-five-year government bonds.
The amount of
compensation was based on the value of the property declared for taxes.
During the first years of the revolution, miners wielded extraordinary
influence within the government. In part, this influence was based on the
miners' decisive role in
the fighting of April 1952. In addition, however, armed militias of
miners formed by the government to counterbalance the military had become
a powerful force in
their own right. Miners immediately organized the Bolivian Labor Federation
(COB), which demanded radical change as well as participation in the government
and
benefits for its members. As a result, the government included three
pro-COB ministers in the cabinet and accepted the demand for fuero sindical,
the legally
autonomous status that granted the COB semisovereign control over the
workers of Bolivia. The MNR regime gave worker representatives veto power
in all
Comibol decisions and allowed for a cogovernment in mine administration.
The government also established special stores for the miners, increased
their salaries, and rehired fired workers.
The peasants also exerted a powerful influence. At first, the government
was unable to control the occupation of land by the peasants. As a result,
it could not
enforce the provisions of the land reform decree to keep medium-sized
productive estates intact. But the MNR eventually gained the support of
the campesinos
when the Ministry of Peasant Affairs was created and when peasants
were organized into syndicates. Peasants were not only granted land but
their militias also were
given large supplies of arms. The peasants remained a powerful political
force in Bolivia during all subsequent governments.
Although these major steps were never reversed, observers have regarded
the revolution as unfinished because it lost momentum after the first years.
The divisions
within the MNR seriously weakened its attempt to incorporate the support
of the Indian peasants, the workers, and the middle class for the government.
In 1952 the
MNR was a broad coalition of groups with different interests. Juan
Oquendo Lechín led the left wing of the party and had the support
of the labor sector. Hernán Siles Zuazo represented the right wing
and had the backing of the middle class. Paz Estenssoro was initially the
neutral leader. Because the majority of the MNR elite
wanted a moderate course and the left wing demanded radical change,
the polarization increased and led eventually to the destruction of the
MNR in 1964.
The country faced severe economic problems as a result of the changes
enacted by the government. The nationalization of the mines had a negative
effect on the
economy. The mines of Comibol produced at a loss because of the lack
of technical expertise and capital to modernize the aging plants and nearly
depleted deposits
of low-grade ore. Declining tin prices on the world market contributed
to the economic problems in the mining sector. Nevertheless, workers in
the management of
Comibol increased salaries and the work force by nearly 50 percent.
The decline of agricultural production contributed to the rapidly deteriorating
economy during the first years of the revolution. Although anarchy in the
countryside
was the main reason for the decrease in production, the peasants' inability
to produce for a market economy and the lack of transport facilities contributed
to the
problem. The attempt to increase agricultural production by colonizing
the less densely populated valleys was not successful at first. As a result,
the food supply for
the urban population decreased, and Bolivia had to import food.
High inflation, primarily caused by social spending, also hurt the economy.
The value of the peso, Bolivia's former currency, fell from 60 to 12,000
to the United
States dollar between 1952 and 1956, affecting primarily the urban
middle class, which began to support the opposition.
The bankrupt economy increased the factionalism within the MNR. Whereas
the left wing demanded more government control over the economy, the right
wing
hoped to solve the nation's problems with aid from the United States.
The government had sought cooperation with the United States as early as
1953, a move that
had given the United States influence over Bolivia's economy. Because
of United States pressure, the Bolivian government promised to compensate
the owners of
nationalized tin mines and drew up a new petroleum code, which again
allowed United States investments in Bolivian oil.
During the presidency of Siles Zuazo (1956-60 and 1982-85), who won
the election with 84 percent of the vote, United States aid reached its
highest level. In 1957
the United States subsidized more than 30 percent of the Bolivian government's
central budget. Advised by the United States government and the International
Monetary Fund (IMF), the Siles Zuazo regime then in power reduced inflation
with a number of politically dangerous measures, such as the freezing of
wages and
the ending of the government-subsidized miners' stores.
Siles Zuazo's stabilization plan seriously damaged the coalition between
the MNR and the COB. The COB called immediately for a general strike, which
threatened
to destroy an already disrupted economy; the strike was called off
only after impassioned appeals by the president. But the conflict between
the government and the
miners' militias continued as the militias constantly challenged the
government's authority. Siles Zuazo faced not only labor unrest in the
mines but also discontent in
the countryside, where peasant leaders were competing for power. In
an effort to quell the unrest, he decided to rebuild the armed forces.
During the Siles Zuazo administration, the strength of the armed forces
grew as a result of a new concern for professionalism and training, technical
assistance from
the United States, and an increase in the size and budget of the military.
In addition, the military's role in containing unrest gave it increasing
influence within the MNR
government.
Although the stabilization plan and the strengthening of the armed forces
were resented by Lechín's faction of the party, the first formal
dissent came from Walter
Guevara Arze and the MNR right wing. Guevara Arze, who had been foreign
minister and then minister of government in the first Paz Estenssoro government,
split
from the MNR to form the Authentic Nationalist Revolutionary Movement
(MNRA) in 1960, when his presidential hopes were destroyed by Paz Estenssoro's
candidacy. Guevara Arze charged that the MNR had betrayed the revolution,
and he posed a formidable opposition in the presidential election of 1960.
Conflicts within the MNR increased during Paz Estenssoro's second term
(1960-64). Together with the United States and the Federal Republic of
Germany (West
Germany), Paz Estenssoro endorsed the "Triangular Plan," which called
for a restructuring of the tin-mining industry. The plan demanded the end
of the workers'
control over Comibol operations, the firing of workers, and a reduction
in their salaries and benefits; it was strongly opposed by the COB and
Lechín's MNR
faction.
In 1964 Paz Estenssoro decided to run again for president, using a revision
of the 1961 Constitution that would allow for a consecutive term, and he
forced his
nomination at a party convention. Lechín, who had hoped to become
the presidential candidate, broke away to form the National Leftist Revolutionary
Party
(PRIN). With his support in the MNR dwindling and opposition from the
labor sector mounting, Paz Estenssoro accepted General René Barrientos
Ortuño as vice
presidential candidate. Because most opposition groups abstained, Paz
Estenssoro was reelected with the support of the military and the peasants.
Paz Estenssoro
had come to rely increasingly on the military, whose role as a peacekeeper
had made it an arbiter in politics. But this support was to prove unreliable;
the military
was already planning to overthrow him. Moreover, rivalry among peasant
groups often resulted in bloody feuds that further weakened the Paz Estenssoro
government.
During its twelve-year rule, the MNR had failed to build a firm basis
for democratic, civilian government. Increasing factionalism, open dissent,
ideological
differences, policy errors, and corruption weakened the party and made
it impossible to establish an institutional framework for the reforms.
Not even the peasants,
who were the main beneficiaries of the revolution, consistently supported
the MNR.